Open access
Forum
Sep 7, 2023

Navier’s 1832 Contributions to the Finance, Governance, and Evaluation of Public Works

Publication: Journal of Hydraulic Engineering
Volume 149, Issue 11

Abstract

Forum papers are thought-provoking opinion pieces or essays founded in fact, sometimes containing speculation, on a civil engineering topic of general interest and relevance to the readership of the journal. The views expressed in this Forum article do not necessarily reflect the views of ASCE or the Editorial Board of the journal.
In 1832, the French journal Annales des Ponts et Chaussées published a paper by the engineer Claude-Louis Navier entitled “On the Execution of Public Works, Particularly Concessions” (Navier 1832). Although known to most engineers for his mathematical foundations of fluid mechanics, Navier was active more broadly in forming today’s fields of transportation engineering, structural engineering, engineering mechanics, engineering finance and management, and economics, as well as fluid mechanics (Cannone and Friedlander 2003).
In the late 1700s and early 1800s, French engineering led the systematic development and application of mathematics and early enlightenment thinking to a wide range of practical and societal problems (Langins 2004; Hayek 1952). The successes of this organized rational and mechanistic approach to understanding and solving problems has led to the intellectual and practical success of engineering and the incorporation of these ideas in economics, business, and industry. In this historical development, many engineers of the early and mid-1800s, particularly from the French École des Ponts et Chaussées and École Polytechnique, made contributions that became fundamental within and outside of engineering.
The contributions of this paper by Navier to economics and public policy were noted by Ekelund and Hébert (1999, pp. 74–77). These contributions are in two categories: (1) early phrasing of the fundamental principle of benefit–cost analysis, and (2) identification and discussion of the means of financing and organizing public works.
The benefit–cost principle is best known today from the US Flood Control Act of 1936 as “the benefits to whomsoever they may accrue are in excess of the estimated costs.” This common-sense principle has been applied at least since 1708, when it was applied by Abbé de Saint-Pierre (Jiang and Marggraf 2021). Navier’s paper formally states this as, “It is easy to see that, for this operation to not be onerous for taxpayers, the annual saving on transportation must at least equal the interest on capital expended, plus maintenance costs.” (Navier 1832, p. 16)
Such an idea appears to have been common among French engineers of that time, such as Courtois in 1833 (Theocharis 1988). Navier’s student, the famous Jules Dupuit, further developed this concept into the theory of consumers’ surplus in 1844 (Dupuit 1844), which became the foundation of modern microeconomics (Ekelund and Hébert 1973, 1999) and is seen as a foundation of modern benefit–cost analysis (Maneschi 1996).
In terms of financing and organizing public works, Navier identified four “means to execute public works” (Navier 1832, p. 4):
“We can distinguish the execution of public works mainly by the following financial means:
1.
Local taxes or levys.
2.
The payment of expenses on state funds, these expenses being taken immediately from budgeted funds, or else with funds provided by loans, so interest and reimbursement are taken from budgets in future years;.
3.
Covering expenses with state funds, with the imposition of a toll to reimburse the money spent and to support maintenance costs.
4.
Execution by way of concession, which requires establishing a toll.”
These fundamental approaches to public works finance and organization introduced in Navier’s paper remain relevant today. He then goes on to discuss the advantages and disadvantages of each approach with considerable insight.
Navier summarized this work as follows:
1.
“The value of public works, aimed to establish transportation, mainly consists in reducing the part of transportation costs charged to commerce. The decrease in this part of transportation expenses is much more important to the progress of agriculture and industry than decreasing the portion of expenses generally supported by the state.
2.
It would be desirable that the expenditure on the works in question should be from tax payments, which would make it possible not to establish tolls, or to establish only very modest tolls intended to pay only maintenance expenses. These works would then provide all the utility that can be expected. This would accelerate the progress of wealth, and the resources of the state could be brought to those parts where they are most needed.
3.
The execution of public works by concession must not be excluded; on the contrary, it must be welcomed and encouraged, because the results are useful, albeit in a much lesser degree.
4.
In granting concessions for the works, the government, the protector of public interests, has duties to fulfill, which consist principally in verifying the general utility of the enterprises, in guaranteeing the interests of commerce by the proper establishment of toll rates, and to ensure the completion of the works.
5.
These conditions cannot be fulfilled without obliging bidders to submit project details, and without subjecting the elements of the enterprise to an in-depth discussion, which may be entrusted to commissions composed in part of independent persons. It is not enough to reduce companies’ prices by public bidding.” (Navier 1832, p. 30)
Today, many of these conclusions and insights are fundamental to the finance and management of civil engineering and public works.
Navier’s French engineering tradition, of which modern American engineering education is a direct descendant, began in the 1700s as an instrument for the centralization of state power (beginning with Louis IV, and continuing to Napoleon in the 19th century) (Langins 2004). As early French engineers addressed initial practical military, transportation, and structural problems, they saw a need to expand engineering’s formal mechanics approach to economic, finance, and ultimately social problems to achieve efficiencies and broader societal objectives. Today’s theories of capitalist economics and socialism both have roots in the work of Navier and his colleagues (Ekelund and Hébert 1999; Hayek 1952).
In our current age of specialization, Navier’s career and contributions remind us that serious generalists also are needed, who can put entire projects together in a larger social and economic context and can develop specialties that contribute well within the larger problem-solving context. Indeed, the general approach of engineering developed by Navier and many others in this era has proven itself to be as valuable for solving broad societal and technical problems as for solving the narrower problems of specialists. In this, effective generalists must be unafraid of specialist details, and also can contribute to specialist details and fundamentals. Navier’s overall interest and diverse engineering contributions were to create infrastructure that functions reliably and economically for the society as a whole. Although the importance of Navier’s well-known fundamental formalization of fluid dynamics is clear for the wide range of hydraulic structures and operations, these engineering accomplishments and others also reflect Navier’s fundamental insights into the governance and finance of public works.
A full translation of the original paper in French is included in the Supplemental Materials to this essay. The English translation should make this work more available to engineers, economists, and scholars of infrastructure economics and policy; to hydraulic engineers interested in the broader contributions of founders of fluid mechanics; and to engineers and engineering students generally to show how many great engineers contribute as serious generalists. This translation is for contemporary engineering and public policy readers. Therefore, when several ways of translating were available, English wording was chosen to make the meaning more readable and understandable for modern professionals and students. (This process made me sympathetic to the difficulties of creating useful translations.)

Supplemental Materials

File (supplemental materials_jhend8.hyeng-13689_lund.pdf)

Data Availability Statement

No data, models, or code were generated or used during the study.

References

Cannone, M., and S. Friedlander. 2003. “Navier: Blow-up and collapse.” Not. AMS 50 (1): 7–13.
Dupuit, J. 1844. “On the measurement of the utility of public works.” Int. Econ. Pap. 2 (1952): 83–110.
Ekelund, R. B., Jr., and R. F. Hébert. 1973. “Public economics at the Ecole des Ponts et Chaussees: 1830–1850.” J. Public Econ. 2 (3): 241–256. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(73)90016-9.
Ekelund, R. B., Jr., and R. F. Hébert. 1999. Secret origins of modern microeconomics: Dupuit and the engineers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, F. A. 1952. The counter-revolution of science: Studies on the abuse of reason, 415. Carmel, CA: Liberty Fund.
Jiang, W., and R. Marggraf. 2021. “The origin of cost–benefit analysis: A comparative view of France and the United States.” Cost Eff. Resour. Allocation 19 (1): 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12962-021-00330-3.
Langins, J. 2004. Conserving the enlightenment—French military engineering from Vauban to the revolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Maneschi, A. 1996. “Jules Dupuit: A sesquicentennial tribute to the founder of benefit-cost analysis.” Eur. J. Hist. Econ. Thought 3 (3): 411–432. https://doi.org/10.1080/10427719600000040.
Navier, C. L. 1832. “De L’Execution des Travaux Publics, et particulièrement des concessions.” Annales des Ponts Et Chaussées. Accessed February 2, 1832. https://gallica.bnf.fr/ark:/12148/cb34348188q/date1832.
Theocharis, R. D. 1988. “C. Courtois: An early contributor to cost-benefit analysis.” Hist. Political Econ. 20 (2): 265–273. https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-20-2-265.

Information & Authors

Information

Published In

Go to Journal of Hydraulic Engineering
Journal of Hydraulic Engineering
Volume 149Issue 11November 2023

History

Received: Mar 4, 2023
Accepted: May 9, 2023
Published online: Sep 7, 2023
Published in print: Nov 1, 2023
Discussion open until: Feb 7, 2024

Authors

Affiliations

Jay Lund, Dist.M.ASCE [email protected]
Distinguished Professor, Dept. of Civil and Environmental Engineering, Univ. of California, Davis, Davis, CA 95616. Email: [email protected]

Metrics & Citations

Metrics

Citations

Download citation

If you have the appropriate software installed, you can download article citation data to the citation manager of your choice. Simply select your manager software from the list below and click Download.

View Options

Media

Figures

Other

Tables

Share

Share

Copy the content Link

Share with email

Email a colleague

Share