Abstract

The advent of smart metering is set to revolutionize many aspects of the relationship between water utilities and their customers, and this includes the possibility of using time-varying water prices as a demand management strategy. These dynamic tariffs could promote water use efficiency by reflecting the variations of water demand, availability, and delivery costs over time. This paper relates the potential benefits of dynamic water tariffs, at the utility and basin scale, to their design across a range of timescales. On one end of the spectrum, subdaily peak pricing shifts use away from peak hours to lower a utility’s operational and capital expenses. On the other end, scarcity pricing factors in the variations of the marginal opportunity cost of water at weekly or longer timescales in the river basin from which water is withdrawn. Dynamic pricing schemes that act across timescales can be devised to yield both types of benefits. The analysis estimates these benefits separately for Greater London (United Kingdom) and its 15 million inhabitants. Scarcity pricing implemented on a weekly timescale equates the marginal cost of residential water with estimates of the marginal economic values of environmental-recreational flows derived from tourism, property values, etc. Scarcity pricing during droughts could result in a 22–63% average reduction in environmental flow shortage while residential price increases would be capped at 150% of base levels. Yet, its ability to protect environmental flows could decrease in extreme shortage situations. The net present value of savings from peak pricing is conservatively evaluated at approximately £10 million for each initial percentage point in daily peak-hour price increase.

Introduction

Smart metering is garnering increasing attention for its potential to bring about new ways of managing water demand (Boyle et al. 2013; Cominola et al. 2015a). Although volumetric water pricing is effective in controlling residential water demand (Olmstead and Stavins 2009; Grafton et al. 2011) when consumers have regular information on pricing (Gaudin 2006) and on their own consumption (Strong and Goemans 2015), residential water pricing policies are still generally based on fixed pricing schedules designed to cover average costs.
The advent of high-resolution smart water metering makes the design of daily and even hourly variable fares feasible (e.g., Vašak et al. 2014), contrary to ordinary metering that provides a measurement only when read manually. The information this generates can help users to understand how to modulate their daily water consumption for different end uses, such as showering, laundry, and garden watering, to manage their water bills. Indeed, high temporal resolution water consumption data retrieved from smart meters enables the extraction of end-use consumption data (e.g., Piga et al. 2016; Creaco et al. 2017) and to profile water customers’ behaviors in response to external stimuli, including pricing schemes and awareness campaigns (e.g., Nguyen et al. 2013; Cominola et al. 2015b). This information could be conveyed either through regular water bills or real-time feedback provided by phone applications and/or in-home displays, prototypes of which are being conceived (e.g., Rizzoli et al. 2014).
The idea of time-differentiation of residential prices per unit consumed dates to the 1970s in the electricity sector (e.g., Atkinson 1979). It soon led to the concept of dynamic pricing, based on the idea that efficient pricing should, with a time resolution of an hour or less, equate power prices with the marginal (incremental) cost of producing electricity and conveying it through the grid (Rosenfeld et al. 1986). Since then, ever more sophisticated schemes have been proposed to manage demand during periods of peak loading in the power network (Herter 2007; Faruqui and Sergici 2010; Joskow and Wolfram 2012; Siano 2014).
Similar to power networks, water distribution infrastructure experiences stress at peak hour. Daily demand varies year-round, and within-day demand is generally characterized by morning and evening peaks (Lucas et al. 2010; Cole and Stewart 2013; Beal and Stewart 2014). Peak-hour demand during the days when consumption is highest impacts network design and capacity expansion. Different parameters exist in the literature to describe an annual maximum in daily demand, including peak day (Lucas et al. 2010; Beal and Stewart 2014; Gurung et al. 2015), peak week (Padula et al. 2013), or mean day maximum month (Gurung et al. 2014). Regardless of which is used, reducing peak demand leads to substantial financial savings at the utility scale (Cole et al. 2012; Gurung et al. 2014).
At the river basin scale, the marginal economic value of water evolves on weekly or longer timescales, which is much slower than for electricity because of the significant natural and artificial storage capacity that typically exists in water systems. Marginal water values increase when water becomes scarce, and therefore using rising water prices as a signal of this scarcity is an appealing way of promoting a more efficient allocation of a limited supply of water over time and across uses (Young 1996; Griffin 2006; Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2008, 2013; Ward and Pulido-Velazquez 2012; Macian-Sorribes et al. 2015). One example in which this approach has been backed by regulation is in Europe with the Water Framework Directive (European Union Commission 2000) and subsequent efforts (e.g., European Union Commission 2012), which promote the inclusion of environmental and resource costs in the calculation of recovery costs for water services. Such regulation also regards water pricing as an instrument to create incentives for efficient water use (Riegels et al. 2013). The concept of resource cost has been linked to the opportunity cost of water use under scarcity (Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2006; Heinz et al. 2007; Tilmant et al. 2008). In these circumstances, unadjusted water use would impose an opportunity cost on other users. Scarcity-induced pricing would signal this to residential users.
To help bridge the gap between the practice of residential water tariffs and the possibilities offered by smart metering, this paper links tariff design across a range of timescales to potential benefits at the utility and river basin scale. In particular, tariffs that use subdaily price variations can be designed to yield benefits by reducing the cost of supply in distribution networks, whereas weekly or monthly variations are appropriate for scarcity pricing. This exploratory paper focuses on these two timescales separately, but readers should keep in mind that tariffs that mix these timescales might be able to yield benefits at both the utility and river basin scale. Tariff changes at annual or longer timescales to reflect investments that affect the supply-demand balance also have impacts at both organizational scales (Sahin et al. 2016), but they do not require the use of smart meters, and are therefore not the focus of this work.
The remaining sections are as follows. First, dynamic tariffs are presented through economic concepts. Following that, potential benefits at the scale of the utility and river basin are presented. They are then evaluated separately for London’s water resource system. Finally, result implications and limitations are discussed, and concluding remarks are presented.

Economics of Tariff Design

Managing Demand through Dynamic Tariffs

Price changes from the baseline price, p0, to a new price, p1, can be used to manage demand over any arbitrary period of time—e.g., hour, day, or week. They aim to achieve a relative change (X) in demand (D), with X<0 in the case of a demand reduction
D(p1)D(p0)=1+X
(1)
This work uses the concept of price elasticity of demand to compare the relative proportions by which demand varies when price varies at the utility scale
E(p)=dD/Ddp/p
(2)
This elasticity is generally negative because demand typically decreases when prices increase. Besides, residential water demand is price inelastic, i.e., the relative change in water consumption is smaller than the relative change in price (Espey et al. 1997; Dalhuisen et al. 2003; Sebri 2014). Using Eqs. (1) and (2), elasticity E(p) determines the relationship between price change from p0 to p1 and the target demand change X
exp(p0p1E(p)dpp)=1+X
(3)
This relationship is described by the demand curve (Fig. 1).
Fig. 1. Residential water demand curve aggregated at the utility level, and tariff changing volumetric price from p0 to p1 (here, a price increase to reduce demand); rectangles represent utility revenue as the product of demand and volumetric price
Because residential water demand is price inelastic, immediate effects of a higher (lower) price are a revenue gain (loss) for utilities and a financial loss (gain) to customers as a whole and diverse outcomes for the individual customers. Tariff design should therefore comprise a revenue target while ensuring the sustainable provision of water services. To ensure a revenue target while managing demand, it is sufficient for the marginal value of residential water to be at p1 (Fig. 1). For instance with a price increase, there is an excess revenue which can be forsaken through tariff design not to increase overall payments by customers.
More generally, dynamic tariffs designed with efficiency objectives have regulatory, financial, and social implications that should not be overlooked. For instance, tariffs should sustain utilities’ financial flexibility in planning for an uncertain future (Hill and Symmonds 2011; Sahin et al. 2016), yet that should be balanced with the imperative of serving and protecting customers (Ofwat 2009).

Subdaily Demand Shifting

Over smaller time frames such as a day (or a week, if weekdays demand is shifted to weekends), some end uses can be shifted from times when prices are higher towards times when they are lower. In theory, there can be an arbitrary number of different prices, but experience from the electricity sector indicates that the many users may be unwilling or unable to implement sophisticated scheduling strategies (Hubert and Grijalva 2012), which would thwart the objective of shifting demand. The simplest demand shifting tariffs, and the easiest to understand for customers, considers only two periods, with the objective of shifting demand from Periods 1 to 2 (Fig. 2).
Fig. 2. Residential water demand curve disaggregated between two periods and demand shifting tariff; rectangles represent utility revenue as the product of demand and volumetric price
Subdaily demand shifting tariffs are expected to provoke a more elastic demand response than tariffs that apply over longer timescales (Cole et al. 2012) because over subdaily timescales, users can shift portions of their uses towards off-peak hours. Assuming elasticities E1 and E2 for both time periods, Eq. (3) also applies to demand shifting and can be used to design a two-period tariff with a revenue target.

Potential Benefits of Dynamic Water Pricing

In principle, benefits are expected to come from efficient pricing, i.e., by defining residential prices according to the marginal cost of supply. Hydroeconomic modeling (Harou et al. 2009) enables the computation of the opportunity cost of water in a river basin at weekly or longer timescales (Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2008, 2013), but to the best of our knowledge, network engineers and water economists have yet to team up to produce methodologies that would evaluate the marginal cost function of peak demands in a pipe network. Therefore, utility-scale benefits focus instead on the direct financial and engineering impacts of reducing peak demand.

Utility-Scale Benefits

Reducing peak demand, e.g., through peak pricing, lowers the cost of a water distribution network operation, maintenance, and expansion. It has the potential to reduce the size of new mains when a city expands and new areas have to be served (Carragher et al. 2012; Lucas et al. 2010), or during the replacement of leaky mains in network maintenance operations; both translate into financial savings. Alternatively, peak pricing can help delay investment in new mains by postponing the date at which existing mains will no longer be able to handle a rising demand and by lowering the risk of pipe bursts caused by high pressure. Pressure management is a recent subfield of water distribution network design and management (see e.g., Gomes et al. 2011; Vicente et al. 2016). Yet, available literature does not seem to address the potential impacts of reducing peak use on pressure management.
Besides, reducing peak demand is expected to reduce operational costs. It could lower peak-hour energy consumption because the daily morning and evenings water use peaks often correspond to times of peak-hour electricity tariffs. Therefore, if a utility does not have enough in-network water storage, it must incur higher energy costs to deliver water during peak time. Optimal pumping scheduling then becomes a significant source of savings (McCormick and Powell 2003; Martínez et al. 2007), and reducing peak use can add substantially to these operational savings. Alternatively, if a utility has enough in-network storage, but expects peak demand to grow, reducing peak use delays the investment in new in-network storage.

Basin-Scale Benefits

The opportunity cost of scarce water allocation over time and across uses can be determined from the marginal value of water (e.g., Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2008), which will depend on the cross-sectoral value of water, from all other uses—e.g., agricultural, industrial, and environmental. Net benefits from water allocation in a river basin are maximal when the net marginal benefits per additional unit of water are equal in all use sectors. For the case of two sectors, or when an efficient cross-sectoral price of water already exists for all nonresidential uses, this equimarginality principle can be illustrated graphically (Fig. 3; Young 1996) by representing the demand curves for residential (from upper left to lower bottom) and for other uses (from the right-hand axis).
Fig. 3. Residential water pricing for decreasing levels of water availability—increasing levels of scarcity
In a nonscarcity situation (left panel on Fig. 3), there is enough water for all competing uses, so water itself has no value. Then, residential water is delivered at its base volumetric rate p0, which is typically a reflection of the utility’s average costs in the common case in which prices equal average cost. On the contrary, when there is water scarcity (right panel on Fig. 3), the two curves are crossing, and the optimal allocation corresponds to the price given by their intersection—if prices reflect marginal opportunity costs. This price π represents the marginal economic value of water as a resource, also referred to by economists as its shadow value. Scarcity price ps at the tap is then given by
ps=π+p0
(4)
Fig. 3 along with Eq. (4) serve as a basis for determining cross-sectoral and residential water prices and associated consumptions.

Greater London Application: Data and Methodology

Context

London, United Kingdom (U.K.) is an administrative entity comprising more than 8.5 million (M) inhabitants, at the core of a metropolitan area topping 13 M inhabitants. Population in that area is growing, fueling concerns about future water supplies in the Thames River basin, which is already classified as water stressed (Environment Agency 2007). These concerns have motivated Thames Water, the utility that serves most of Greater London, to launch a 15-year smart metering roll out set to equip a sizable proportion of the 3.3 M households they serve (Rasekh et al. 2016).
The purpose of this case study is to give order-of-magnitude estimates of the possible concrete benefits of dynamic pricing, not to provide precise figures. This proof of concept is meant to help motivate water utilities and other stakeholders to consider the potential utility-scale and basin-scale benefits. Another aim is to pinpoint what the data limitations are, so as to motivate the development of more accurate estimates.

Dynamic Pricing and Demand Response

This application proposes an economic engineering (Lund et al. 2006) approach for evaluating the benefits of smart-metered enabled dynamic pricing mechanisms. It considers two tariffs. A sub-daily peak pricing scheme aims at reducing peak-hour residential demand for financial utility-scale benefits. A scarcity pricing scheme, with prices changing every week, aims at a more efficient use of available water in the Thames River basin, especially when it comes to the environmental benefits of Thames waters.
Peak demand is generally peak-hour demand at the most use-intensive time of year, so that peak pricing can be achieved by shifting demand from a peak Period 1 to an off-peak Period 2 (similar to Fig. 2), possibly combined with demand management during a well-identified period of exceptional peak demand. Scarcity pricing implements variable prices on a regular basis—e.g., weekly—to track the variations in water availability, and in water value.
The demand curve for residential water is derived using the point expansion method (Jenkins et al. 2003; Griffin 2006), assuming a constant price elasticity E in both assessments of peak and scarcity pricing. Eq. (3) becomes
p1=p0·(1+X)1/E
(5)
where p0=£2.05 per m3 = total 2016 uniform volumetric water price by Thames Water (Thames Water 2015). In the absence of real-world trials for dynamic water tariffs such as those investigated in this London case study, or of any indication of how smart metering and dynamic pricing may impact the price response, three time-invariant estimates of the price elasticity of water demand are used, E0.3, 0.4 and 0.5. They come from a recent study that introduced a new approach to extrapolate results from a meta-analysis of the price elasticity of residential demand (Marzano et al. 2017).

Partial Estimation of Utility-Scale Financial Savings

There are gaps in the literature pertaining to impacts of lowered peak-hour demand, and the impacts of daily water demand variations on a water distribution network is still a topic of active research (Liu et al. 2016). Due to data availability, this London case study focuses exclusively on savings due to reduced expansion and replacement costs associated with reducing peak usage. These savings have been estimated using the following steps.
First, lowered peak-hour demand has been analytically linked with reduced costs in mains expansions. Lucas et al. (2010) is one of few studies that explore this relationship. For a newly-built suburb of Melbourne, Australia, they designed the water network according to different estimates of peak consumption. Using data from that work, the authors fitted a quadratic relationship between relative peak usage reduction and the relative cost of new mains (Fig. 4). This quadratic fit is the simplest way to capture both the decreasing cost and the decreasing returns of peak demand reduction in the 0–50% range without overfitting the data. In a similar way, if mains have to be replaced, e.g., because they are leaky, lowering peak use might prompt water managers to replace such leaky existing pipes with smaller ones in areas where consumption is not expected to grow in the future. London’s Victorian mains were first installed in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Because of their age, they are leaky and need to be replaced in the decades to come.
Fig. 4. Quadratic relationship between peak usage reduction and cost of investing in new mains in a residential suburb in Sydney, Australia (data from Lucas et al. 2010)
Second, this evaluation extrapolates the quadratic relationship between peak use and investments in Fig. 4 to both network expansion and replacement in London. This relationship is applied to the average per-property cost of mains installation or replacement, evaluated at £2,000 by two different ways, and confirmed by the figures from Lucas et al. (2010). One evaluation relies on an average cost per meter of mains, whereas the other comes from a per-property cost evaluation from different property types, then averaged thanks to a classification of property by type (Thames Water 2014). The data at the origin of these evaluations is confidential.
Third, this per-property evaluation of savings associated to peak pricing and resulting decrease in peak use is then multiplied by the number of properties for which mains expansion or replacement are needed each year to yield annual utility-wide benefits over a 45-year period (2016–2060). These numbers are derived from (1) population growth projections (Thames Water 2014) that are assumed to reflect the rate of construction of new properties for which new mains will be required, and (2) an estimate of the average rate of replacement of Victorian mains. These two latter numbers are expressed as the number of properties for which mains expansion or replacement are needed each year. Thus, a 200-year turnover is interpreted to be equivalent to installing new mains for 1/200 of the properties during any given year. This very conservative estimate reflects the actual age of some of those mains—more than 100 years old—while leading to conservative estimates on the savings potential of reducing peak use, which is appropriate for a proof of concept study. Computed estimates assume that all 3.3 M properties existing in 2016 are equipped with smart meters and have a peak pricing tariff.
Finally, annual savings are computed over a 45-year period (2016–2060) to find the utility scale net present value (NPV) of savings, using the U.K. government’s reference interest rate (3.5%; HM Treasury 2003). Parameter values are summarized in the second column of Table 1.
Table 1. Sensitivity Analysis of the Financial Benefit Estimate, for a 20% Increase in Peak Price
ParameterValueBenefit sensitivity (20% price increase)
AverageRange (±X)+X (%)X (%)
Price elasticity of demand0.4±0.1%23+22
Annual discount rate3.5%±1%15+19
Per-property cost of mains£2,000±£500+2525
Annual population growth0.6%±0.4+4641
Annual mains replacement rate0.5%±0.2+1818

Basin Model and Scarcity Pricing

The evaluation of the potential basin-scale benefits of scarcity pricing postprocesses results from an adapted version of the IRAS-2010 rule-based simulation model by Matrosov et al. (2011) for the Thames Valley and Greater London [Fig. 5(a)]. This model uses historical flows from 1920–2004 with a weekly time step and combines them with projected demands for 2050. This scenario is supported by the fact that demand increase is expected to play a greater role than changes in supply by midcentury (Thames Water 2014).
Fig. 5. (a) IRAS-2010 model from Matrosov et al. (2011), used for simulating the London water supply-demand; (b) detail of the LAS, London demand node, and environmental flows through London
In the IRAS-2010 model, water use restrictions are enforced there when London’s Aggregated Storage (LAS) drops below certain levels, which vary seasonally according to the Lower Thames Control Diagram (Matrosov et al. 2011). These restrictions lower both London’s water consumption and the minimum Thames River flow requirement at Teddington weir, upstream of London [Fig. 5(b)]. This requirement reflects benefits such as navigation, recreational and environmental values, and reducing it implies losses to these sectors.
This analysis postprocesses simulation results from the IRAS-2010 model. Scarcity pricing impacts are evaluated for the wide range of supply-demand conditions that arise over the course of the 85-year simulation. Scarcity pricing is used to efficiently reallocate water during each weekly time step downstream of LAS. For each time step, postprocessing finds the unique efficient price π that equates the marginal environmental benefits of Thames flow below Teddington weir to the marginal value of raw water for residential use, similar to Fig. 3 and Eq. (4). Yet, for many simulated weeks, results suggest different urban and environmental marginal prices (pu and pe), deduced by reporting the simulated allocation on the demand curves. These prices are made to converge towards the unique efficient price π through a simple dichotomic search that reduces the difference between pu and pe by a factor of at least two at each iteration (see Appendix for details). In this way, water is allocated in an efficient way (the equimarginal principle holds) and the water allocated to both the river and the residential users by the IRAS-2010 simulation model is rebalanced on a week-by-week basis by postprocessing.
Demand curves for both urban and environmental water uses are needed to postprocess IRAS-2010 results and assess the possible impacts of scarcity pricing in London. The residential demand curve is derived from Eq. (5). The environmental demand curve represents the population’s willingness to pay for different levels of environmental flows, and it has not been estimated for London yet. In this data-scarce context, a simple linear environmental demand curve approximation is used, which is consistent with previous theoretical studies (Yang et al. 2009; Giuliani et al. 2014). In this case, it is sufficient to know the aggregate environmental benefits of river flow in the Thames to derive the whole demand curve. Environmental benefits are the area underneath the linear demand curve.
Parameterizing the demand curve is challenging because there are many ways in which river flows are valuable (Kulshreshtha and Gillies 1993). Two willingness-to-pay studies provide a similar evaluation of the environmental value of Thames River flows (Thames Water 2005; Eftec 2015). Both are based on stated-preference studies from respondents in the Thames Water region in the context of the construction of the Thames tideway tunnel, a large new infrastructure aimed at eliminating combined sewers overflow. They report an aggregate annual value of approximately £250 M that encompasses a series of ecosystem services brought by the river thanks to this infrastructure. This annual aggregate value of £250 M is interpreted as a lower bound for the ecosystem value of the Thames’ water, and can therefore be used as a baseline value of environmental flows and then disaggregated at the weekly time step. Specific ecosystem services used by a fraction of the population add to this total, but willingness-to-pay studies report comparatively much smaller value for these (e.g., £12 M for angling, Peirson et al. 2001).
The value for flows in London’s Thames River goes beyond ecosystem services and associated recreational benefits. For instance, riverfront location bolsters the value of both new and existing real estate developments (Cassidy 2013). The river contributes both directly—cruises, touristic attractions, riverfront venues—and indirectly—through its place in popular culture—to tourism revenues, estimated at £15 billion a year from overnight visitors and up to £26 billion a year when accounting for day trips to London (Visit England 2016). Given the amounts at stake, even a minor contribution of a few percentage points to the value of riverfront development and the revenues of tourism might represent several hundred million pounds. To investigate the possible implications for scarcity pricing, total values of instream flows worth £500 M per year and £750 M per year are compared with the base estimate of £250 M per year.

Greater London Application: Results

Financial Savings from Reducing Peak Use

The potential utility scale financial impact on London of peak-hour pricing is computed using the parameter values from the second column of Table 1. Results from Fig. 6 suggest that price increases see diminishing returns, but that doubling or tripling peak prices could have an important impact both on peak consumption and associated benefits. This ability to design and install less costly mains is estimated at approximately £100 to £200 per property NPV of savings—recall that there are 3.3 million properties. This figure is reasonable given NPV saving estimations of AUS $20 M for 30,000 properties in Mackay, Australia, for a 10% reduction in monthly peak demand (Beal and Flynn 2014). These savings come from delayed network investment. Extrapolated over London and its 3.3-M properties, this would correspond to £1 billion NPV, well over the £240 M found by the calculation presented in this section.
Fig. 6. (a) Reduction in peak use; (b) potential financial savings, as a function of peak-hour price increases; in this figure, savings from reduced costs of mains expansion consistently make up 54% of the total
A sensitivity analysis has been performed on the various parameters used for the calculations (Table 1). Results do not contradict the idea that the potential benefits of peak pricing might be worth evaluating further. Uncertainty about future population growth is particularly large (Thames Water 2014), and that translates into a large uncertainty affecting the benefits from less costly mains expansions, which could be almost negated if population growth is only 0.2%, or almost doubled if it reaches 1%; in both cases this has a major impact on the total potential benefits from peak pricing.

Environmental Benefits of Scarcity Pricing in the Lower Thames Basin

Scarcity pricing is postprocessed from IRAS-2010 results for three annual values of environmental flows (£250 M, £500 M, and £750 M) and three values of the price elasticity of demand (E=0.3, 0.4, and 0.5). Recall that each elasticity value represents a possible demand response to price changes; a combination of values of environmental flows and price elasticity defines a scenario. These nine distinct scarcity pricing scenarios are compared with the current rule-based management simulated with the IRAS-2010 simulation model, in which environmental flows are reduced as levels drop in London’s storage reservoirs. Results are summarized in Tables 2 and 3, and the modeled consequences of scarcity pricing on the 1943–1944 drought are presented in Fig. 7.
Table 2. Environmental Flow Shortage for the Rule-Based Allocation Scenario, and over the 85-Year Simulation, for Dynamic Scarcity Pricing under Different Valuations of Environmental Flows and Price Elasticities
Parameter valuesScarcity pricingRule-based allocation
Value of environmental flows£250  M/year£500  M/year£750  M/year
Price elasticity of demandE=0.3E=0.4E=0.5E=0.3E=0.4E=0.5E=0.3E=0.4E=0.5
Average deficit (ML/day)214193175168144126140117101275
Events with flows under 400  ML/day
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)1.761.481.111.081.000.311.000.290.255.29
 Number of events1010997675542
Events with flows under 200  ML/day
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)0.690.290.260.260.220.200.220.200.190.05
 Number of events13555333323
No-flow events
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)0.220.210.200.200.190.160.190.160.160
 Number of events3333242440

Note: ML/day = million liters per day.

Table 3. Residential Price Increases Associated with Dynamic Scarcity Pricing over the 85-Year Simulation
Parameter valuesScarcity pricing
Value of environmental flows£250  M/year£500  M/year£750  M/year
Price elasticity of demandE=0.3E=0.4E=0.5E=0.3E=0.4E=0.5E=0.3E=0.4E=0.5
10% residential price increase
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)10.710.610.610.810.710.710.810.710.7
 Number of events767474777676777876
50% residential price increase
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)1.311.051.002.171.931.495.372.211.93
 Number of events877151110411711
100% residential price increase
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)0001.000.290.251.281.000.31
 Number of events0007551076
150% residential price increase
 Frequency of occurrence (weeks/year)0000.210.200.190.290.220.21
 Number of events000332533
Fig. 7. Scarcity pricing versus rule-based allocation: results for the 1943–1944 drought event for the rule-based allocation scenario, and scarcity pricing with E=0.4 and the three valuations of environmental flows (valuations between parentheses)
Results illustrate that scarcity pricing would reduce environmental flow shortage overall. Shortage events happen almost 25% of the time during rule-based allocation simulations. In those weeks, scarcity pricing leads to 22% average decrease in shortage in the most unfavorable scenario (less elastic demand, lower value of environmental flows), a figure that raises up to 63% in the most favorable scenario. Environmental valuation scenarios have more impact on the results more than price elasticity scenarios, stressing the importance of properly valuing environmental flows. Scarcity pricing is more effective for events of mild severity than for situations of severe shortage (e.g., August to October 1944 on Fig. 7). Then, residential consumers are willing to pay for water even at prices that deplete available water for the environment. This happens regardless of the parameter values chosen, which suggests that during severe drought events, scarcity pricing should sometimes be used alongside other regulatory instruments such as water usage restrictions, lest environmental flows become depleted.
When it comes to price increases, mild increases are very common, but price increases more than 50% happen infrequently and occur more often when environmental flows are valued more. In fact, the sharpest price increases—approximately 150% for E=0.3—correspond to no-flow events in these simulations (Fig. 7). This implies that scarcity-induced price increases are limited in magnitude because they become unnecessary once environmental flows have been depleted. In those situations, pricing would be complemented or even replaced by other regulatory tools.

Discussion

This paper outlines the potential benefits at the utility and river basin scale of dynamic pricing, which can be implemented through price variations at a range of timescales. In particular, the case study application to London provides a proof of concept of the potential of those pricing mechanisms for reaching their objectives. Yet, the water sector is still in the early phases of smart metering diffusion and dynamic pricing implementation. Further assessment of the technological and institutional challenges raised by dynamic pricing will be necessary.
The development of smart metering takes place at a time when new avenues for engaging the public, and modeling their behaviors, are being explored (Fraternali et al. 2012). In particular, user modeling is seen as a promising tool to help design personalized water demand management strategies with highly customized feedbacks (Cominola et al. 2015a; Cardell-Oliver et al. 2016). This can lead to reduced water consumption on its own (Sonderlund et al. 2016). For instance, individually targeted behavioral messages indicate an interesting potential for reducing or shifting residential peak diurnal daily water end-use demand by 8–15% during the morning hours and 12–23% at night (Beal et al. 2016).
Dynamic pricing could therefore support comprehensive strategies that manage demand through a combination of customer engagement, awareness campaigns, detailed personalized feedback on consumptive behavior, and gamification, for example (Harou et al. 2014). Beyond, the complementarity and respective roles of price and nonprice instruments are topics of active research and debate (Michelsen et al. 1999; Inman and Jeffrey 2006; Olmstead and Stavins 2009; Garcia-Valiñas et al. 2015). However, although research on urban water pricing has made significant advances in recent years, greater efforts to collect data and to evaluate alternative regulatory approaches such as use regulations and other nonprice instruments remain necessary (Worthington and Hoffman 2008; Katz et al. 2016).
The possible combinations, of dynamic pricing with use regulation, awareness campaigns, and all the new ways to engage with residential users that are being made available, may have an effect on the price response. Likewise, the price elasticity of demand, which describes this response, is known to evolve over time after a price change (Dalhuisen et al. 2003). Until a dynamic water tariff is trialed in a real-world situation, it may seem bold to make assumptions about how the price response may be impacted by such factors as the time resolution of the tariff, the rhythm and magnitude of the price changes, or the interaction with other smart meter–enabled technologies and policy tools. In addition, in sectors where dynamic pricing has been implemented, surveys of multiple trials (e.g., Faruqui and Sergici 2010, for the power sector) reveal that demand response to price may depend on a number of sector-specific and location-specific factors. This stresses that one should be cautious with assumptions on the price response to dynamic water tariffs in a given context and location. At the same time, evaluating—and demonstrating the potential—benefits of dynamic pricing is a necessary step towards real-world implementation. Therefore, the approach taken in this paper is to evaluate dynamic pricing with simple, neutral assumptions on price response, e.g., by using several constant values for the price elasticity of demand (see e.g., Renzetti et al. 2015).
The case study application also shows the interest of extending environmental flow valuation to all instream usages (e.g., recreation, riverfront property valuation) to represent the interests of all stakeholders. Attempts by ecological and environmental economists to assess the value of protecting instream flow services are increasing and can provide valuable guidance in proposing reasonable scarcity charges. Overall these attempts focus on specific services, such as recreation (Duffield et al. 1992; Weber and Berrens 2006) and protection of aquatic fauna (Berrens et al. 1996) or a wider combination of them (Loomis et al. 2000; Holmes et al. 2004). Possible improvements of instream flow services are highly location-specific and wide in scope. Accordingly, the economic evaluation of direct and indirect resource uses should make use of qualitative, quantitative, and monetary assessments (Eftec 2010), including spatial analysis tools and hydroeconomic modeling.
In this work, scarcity pricing only looks at marginal water values given a total water allocation determined by system rules in a system with limited storage capacity. Yet, the value of water also depends on its future availability. Therefore, scarcity pricing could also be used to balance present and future allocation; this is already the case in some water-scarce river basins with substantial use of intertemporal storage (Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2008; Pulido-Velazquez et al. 2013). In such cases, one must also account for the uncertain nature of future water availability (Tilmant et al. 2008; Macian-Sorribes et al. 2015).

Conclusions

This paper provided an economic engineering conceptual framework for smart meter–enabled dynamic pricing, a proof of concept application to London’s water supply system and a discussion of some salient issues. It starts from the observation that dynamic tariffs can be implemented at a broad range of temporal scales, and that they may be beneficial at the utility and river basin scales.
Dynamic pricing can be used to pursue the objectives of scarcity pricing and peak pricing policies. Scarcity pricing uses tariffs that reflect the marginal opportunity cost given by the value of leaving water in the river for other uses, human or ecological. This pricing is efficient and leads to greater basin-wide benefits from water allocation. Contrary to enforcing demand reductions while charging water at the same fixed rate, it can also lead to water savings without hurting a utility’s finances. Peak pricing uses demand shifting, and sometimes demand reduction, to reduce peak-hour demand. Because water distribution networks are designed to handle demand peaks, these reductions lead to substantial savings in network design, maintenance, and deferred expansion.
Application to London outlines the potential of both pricing schemes. Evaluated using historical flow data, scarcity pricing helped reduce environmental flow shortages in London by approximately half (22–63%) depending on the valuation of these flows and on the demand response. Corresponding residential price increases are relatively limited (prices at least doubled less than 2% of the time). Yet, economic instruments alone may not be able to protect environmental flows in situations of extreme scarcity. The benefits of peak pricing are in terms of network investment; doubling peak-hour prices could result in a conservative estimate of savings of approximately £200 per property in NPV. These results underscore the potential of smart metering to enable demand management of large metropolitan areas that depend on nearby high value environments as their source of water. They also highlight the importance of bridging gaps in research and practice that hinder accurate evaluations of the benefits of dynamic pricing. Last but not least, dynamic pricing impacts utilities’ costs and benefits in the long run, as peak pricing decreases costs and scarcity pricing might raise extra revenues. Dynamic tariffs could therefore be considered as long-term planning instruments by utilities.

Appendix. Finding Efficient Price π

Assume there is limited water availability between two sectors like on Fig. 8, but the allocation is not efficient and favors a sector α above a sector β. Then, scarcity is more felt by the latter than by the former, and pα<π<pβ. To find π, the dichotomic search uses initial values pα0=pα and pβ0=pβ, and then defines [pαk+1,pβk+1] from [pαk,pβk] using pk+1=(pαk+pβk)/2 and the iterative formula
pk+1={pαk+1if  pk+1<πpβk+1if  pk+1π
(6)
Fig. 8. Transition from iteration k to iteration k+1 of the dichotomic search
Because the demand curves are monotonous, to a price pαk+1 (or pβk+1) corresponds a unique way to allocate water. Eq. (6) means to keep pαk<π<pβk for all iterations k of the search. Graphically (Fig. 8), this ensures that the points defined on the demand curves at iteration k+1 are within the triangle defined by A, B, and C at iteration k. It is a smaller triangle, therefore pαkpαk+1<π<pβk+1pβk. Finally, the equation guarantees that pβk+1pαk+1(pβkpαk)/2, which guarantees the convergence of the search.

Data Availability Statement

Data and code generated by the authors or analyzed during the study are available at https://github.com/charlesrouge/Dynamic_Pricing.

Acknowledgments

The work was supported by the research project “SmartH2O: an ICT Platform to leverage on Social Computing for the efficient management of Water Consumption,” funded by the EU Seventh Framework Programme under Grant Agreement No. 619172, and by EPSRC Grant No. EP/G060460/1. The authors wish to thank Anna Wallen for comments on this manuscript, as well as the editor, associate editor David Rosenberg, and three anonymous reviewers, for their constructive comments.

References

Atkinson, S. E. (1979). “Responsiveness to time-of-day electricity pricing: First empirical results.” J. Econometrics, 9(1–2), 79–95.
Beal, C. D., and Flynn, J. (2014). “The 2014 review of smart metering and intelligent water networks in Australia and New Zealand.”, Griffith Univ., Nathan, Australia.
Beal, C. D., Gurung, T. R., and Stewart, R. A. (2016). “Demand-side management for supply-side efficiency: Modeling tailored strategies for reducing peak residential water demand.” Sustainable Prod. Consumption, 6, 1–11.
Beal, C. D., and Stewart, R. A. (2014). “Identifying residential water end uses underpinning peak day and peak hour demand.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04014008.
Berrens, R. P., Ganderton, P., and Silva, C. L. (1996). “Valuing the protection of minimum instream flows in New Mexico.” J. Agric. Resour. Econ., 21(2), 294–308.
Boyle, T., et al. (2013). “Intelligent metering for urban water: A review.” Water, 5(3), 1052–1081.
Cardell-Oliver, R., Wang, J., and Gigney, H. (2016). “Smart meter analytics to pinpoint opportunities for reducing household water use.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04016007.
Carragher, B. J., Stewart, R. A., and Beal, C. D. (2012). “Quantifying the influence of residential water appliance efficiency on average day diurnal demand patterns at an end use level: A precursor to optimised water service infrastructure planning.” Resour. Conserv. Recycl., 62, 81–90.
Cassidy, R. (2013). “River, front and center.” Planning, 79(1), 24–31.
Cole, G., O’Halloran, K., and Stewart, R. A. (2012). “Time of use tariffs: implications for water efficiency.” Water Sci. Technol. Water Supply, 12(1), 90–100.
Cole, G., and Stewart, R. A. (2013). “Smart meter enabled disaggregation of urban peak water demand: Precursor to effective urban water planning.” Urban Water J., 10(3), 174–194.
Cominola, A., Giuliani, M., Piga, D., Castelletti, A., and Rizzoli, A. (2015a). “Benefits and challenges of using smart meters for advancing residential water demand modeling and management: A review.” Environ. Modell. Software, 72, 198–214.
Cominola, A., Giuliani, M., Piga, D., Castelletti, A., Rizzoli, A., and Anda, M. (2015b). “Modelling residential water consumers’ behaviors by feature selection and feature weighting.” Proc., 36th IAHR World Congress, The Hague, Netherlands.
Creaco, E., Blokker, M., and Buchberger, S. (2017). “Models for generating household water demand pulses: Literature review and comparison.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04017013.
Dalhuisen, J. M., Florax, R. J. G. M., de Groot, H. L. F., and Nijkamp, P. (2003). “Price and income elasticities of residential water demand: A meta-analysis.” Land Econ., 79(2), 292–308.
Duffield, J. W., Neher, C. J., and Brown, T. C. (1992). “Recreation benefits of instream flow: Application to montana’s big hole and bitterroot rivers.” Water Resour. Res., 28(9), 2169–2181.
Eftec. (2010). “Scoping study on the economic (or non-market) valuation issues and the implementation of the wfd: Final report.” Defra, London.
Eftec. (2015). “Update of the economic valuation of thames tideway tunnel environmental benefits: Final report.” Defra, London.
Environment Agency. (2007). “Areas of water stress: final classification.”, Bristol, England.
Espey, M., Espey, J., and Shaw, W. D. (1997). “Price elasticity of residential demand for water: A meta-analysis.” Water Resour. Res., 33(6), 1369–1374.
European Union Commission. (2000). “Directive 2000/60/ec of the european parliament and of the council of 23 october 2000 establishing a framework for community action in the field of water policy.” Off. J. L, 327(1), 1–73.
European Union Commission. (2012). “A blueprint to safeguard Europe’s water resources.” European Commission, Brussels, Belgium.
Faruqui, A., and Sergici, S. (2010). “Household response to dynamic pricing of electricity: A survey of 15 experiments.” J. Regul. Econ., 38(2), 193–225.
Fraternali, P., Castelletti, A., Soncini-Sessa, R., Ruiz, C. V., and Rizzoli, A. (2012). “Putting humans in the loop: Social computing for water resources management.” Environ. Modell. Software, 37, 68–77.
Garcia-Valiñas, M. A., Martínez-Espiñeira, R., and To, H. (2015). “The use of non-pricing instruments to manage residential water demand: What have we learned?” Understanding and managing urban water in transition, Springer, Dordrecht, Netherlands, 269–281.
Gaudin, S. (2006). “Effect of price information on residential water demand.” Appl. Econ., 38(4), 383–393.
Giuliani, M., Castelletti, A., Amigoni, F., and Cai, X. (2014). “Multiagent systems and distributed constraint reasoning for regulatory mechanism design in water management.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04014068.
Gomes, R., Marques, A. S., and Sousa, J. (2011). “Estimation of the benefits yielded by pressure management in water distribution systems.” Urban Water J., 8(2), 65–77.
Grafton, R. Q., Ward, M. B., To, H., and Kompas, T. (2011). “Determinants of residential water consumption: Evidence and analysis from a 10-country household survey.” Water Resour. Res., 47(8), W08537.
Griffin, R. C. (2006). “Water resource economics.” The analysis of scarcity, policies, and projects, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Gurung, T. R., Stewart, R. A., Beal, C. D., and Sharma, A. K. (2015). “Smart meter enabled water end-use demand data: Platform for the enhanced infrastructure planning of contemporary urban water supply networks.” J. Clean. Prod., 87, 642–654.
Gurung, T. R., Stewart, R. A., Sharma, A. K., and Beal, C. D. (2014). “Smart meters for enhanced water supply network modelling and infrastructure planning.” Resour. Conserv. Recycling, 90, 34–50.
Harou, J., et al. (2014). “Smart metering, water pricing and social media to stimulate residential water efficiency: Opportunities for the smarth2o project.” Procedia Eng., 89(3–4), 1037–1043.
Harou, J. J., Pulido-Velazquez, M., Rosenberg, D. E., Medellín-Azuara, J., Lund, J. R., and Howitt, R. E. (2009). “Hydro-economic models: Concepts, design, applications, and future prospects.” J. Hydrol., 375(3–4), 627–643.
Heinz, I., Pulido-Velazquez, M., Lund, J. R., and Andreu, J. (2007). “Hydro-economic modeling in river basin management: Implications and applications for the european water framework directive.” Water Resour. Manage., 21(7), 1103–1125.
Herter, K. (2007). “Residential implementation of critical-peak pricing of electricity.” Energy Policy, 35(4), 2121–2130.
Hill, T., and Symmonds, G. (2011). “Sustained water conservation by combining incentives, data and rates to effect consumer behavioural change.” WIT Trans. Ecol. Environ., 153, 409–420.
HM Treasury. (2003). “The green book on appraisal and evaluation in central government.” U.K. Government, London.
Holmes, T. P., Bergstrom, J. C., Huszar, E., Kask, S. B., and Orr, F. (2004). “Contingent valuation, net marginal benefits, and the scale of riparian ecosystem restoration.” Ecol. Econ., 49(1), 19–30.
Hubert, T., and Grijalva, S. (2012). “Modeling for residential electricity optimization in dynamic pricing environments.” IEEE Trans. Smart Grid, 3(4), 2224–2231.
Inman, D., and Jeffrey, P. (2006). “A review of residential water conservation tool performance and influences on implementation effectiveness.” Urban Water J., 3(3), 127–143.
Jenkins, M. W., Lund, J. R., and Howitt, R. E. (2003). “Using economic loss functions to value urban water scarcity in california.” J. Am. Water Works Assn., 95(2), 58–70.
Joskow, P. L., and Wolfram, C. D. (2012). “Dynamic pricing of electricity.” Am. Econ. Rev., 102(3), 381–385.
Katz, D., Grinstein, A., Kronrod, A., and Nisan, U. (2016). “Evaluating the effectiveness of a water conservation campaign: Combining experimental and field methods.” J. Environ. Manage., 180, 335–343.
Kulshreshtha, S., and Gillies, J. (1993). “The economic value of the south saskatchewan river to the city of saskatoon: (i) valuation framework and value estimates for selected uses.” Can. Water Resour. J., 18(3), 199–215.
Liu, Y., Sun, F., Zeng, S., Lauzon, K., and Dong, X. (2016). “Integrated model driven by agent-based water end-use forecasting to evaluate the performance of water and wastewater pipeline systems.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04016035.
Loomis, J., Kent, P., Strange, L., Fausch, K., and Covich, A. (2000). “Measuring the total economic value of restoring ecosystem services in an impaired river basin: Results from a contingent valuation survey.” Ecol. Econ., 33(1), 103–117.
Lucas, S. A., Coombes, P. J., and Sharma, A. K. (2010). “The impact of diurnal water use patterns, demand management and rainwater tanks on water supply network design.” Water Sci. Technol. Water Supply, 10(1), 69–80.
Lund, J. R., Cai, X., and Characklis, G. W. (2006). “Economic engineering of environmental and water resource systems.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 399–402.
Macian-Sorribes, H., Pulido-Velazquez, M., and Tilmant, A. (2015). “Definition of efficient scarcity-based water pricing policies through stochastic programming.” Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci., 19(9), 3925–3935.
Martínez, F., Hernández, V., Alonso, J. M., Rao, Z., and Alvisi, S. (2007). “Optimizing the operation of the Valencia water-distribution network.” J. Hydroinf., 9(1), 65–78.
Marzano, R., Rougé, C., Garrone, P., Grilli, L., Harou, J., and Pulido-Velazquez, M. (2017). “Data-driven explorations of the determinants of the price response to residential water tariffs: Meta-analysis and beyond.” Environ. Modell. Software, in press.
Matrosov, E. S., Harou, J. J., and Loucks, D. P. (2011). “A computationally efficient open-source water resource system simulator application to London and the Thames basin.” Environ. Modell. Software, 26(12), 1599–1610.
McCormick, G., and Powell, R. S. (2003). “Optimal pump scheduling in water supply systems with maximum demand charges.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 372–379.
Michelsen, A. M., McGuckin, J. T., and Stumpf, D. (1999). “Nonprice water conservation programs as a demand management tool.” J. Am. Water Resour. Assoc., 35(3), 593–602.
Nguyen, K. A., Zhang, H., and Stewart, R. A. (2013). “Development of an intelligent model to categorise residential water end use events.” J. Hydro-environ. Res., 7(3), 182–201.
Ofwat. (2009). “Future water and sewerage charges 2010-15: Final determinations.” ⟨http://www.ofwat.gov.uk/wp-content/uploads/2015/11/det_pr09_finalfull.pdf⟩ (Feb. 12, 2016).
Olmstead, S. M., and Stavins, R. N. (2009). “Comparing price and nonprice approaches to urban water conservation.” Water Resour. Res., 45(4), W04301.
Padula, S., Harou, J., Papageorgiou, L., Ji, Y., Ahmad, M., and Hepworth, N. (2013). “Least economic cost regional water supply planning: Optimising infrastructure investments and demand management for south east England’s 17.6 million people.” Water Resour. Manage., 27(15), 5017–5044.
Peirson, G., Tingley, D., Spurgeon, J., and Radford, A. (2001). “Economic evaluation of inland fisheries in England and Wales.” Fish. Manage. Ecol., 8(4–5), 415–424.
Piga, D., Cominola, A., Giuliani, M., Castelletti, A., and Rizzoli, A. E. (2016). “Sparse optimization for automated energy end use disaggregation.” IEEE Trans. Control Syst. Technol., 24(3), 1044–1051.
Pulido-Velazquez, M., Alvarez-Mendiola, E., and Andreu, J. (2013). “Design of efficient water pricing policies integrating basinwide resource opportunity costs.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 583–592.
Pulido-Velazquez, M., Andreu, J., Sahuquillo, A., and Pulido-Velazquez, D. (2008). “Hydro-economic river basin modelling: The application of a holistic surface-groundwater model to assess opportunity costs of water use in Spain.” Ecol. Econ., 66(1), 51–65.
Pulido-Velazquez, M., Joaquin, A., and Sahuquillo, A. (2006). “Economic optimization of conjunctive use of surface water and groundwater at the basin scale.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 454–467.
Rasekh, A., Hassanzadeh, A., Mulchandani, S., Modi, S., and Banks, M. K. (2016). “Smart water networks and cyber security.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 01816004.
Renzetti, S., Brandes, O. M., Dupont, D. P., MacIntyre-Morris, T., and Stinchcombe, K. (2015). “Using demand elasticity as an alternative approach to modelling future community water demand under a conservation-oriented pricing system: An exploratory investigation.” Can. Water Resour. J., 40(1), 62–70.
Riegels, N., et al. (2013). “Systems analysis approach to the design of efficient water pricing policies under the EU water framework directive.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 574–582.
Rizzoli, A., et al. (2014). “The SmartH2O project and the role of social computing in promoting efficient residential water use: A first analysis.” Proc., 7th Int. Congress on Environmental Modelling and Software, D. Ames, N. Quinn, and A. Rizzoli, eds., iEMSs, Manno, Switzerland.
Rosenfeld, A. H., Bulleit, D. A., and Peddie, R. A. (1986). “Smart meters and spot pricing: Experiments and potential.” IEEE Technol. Soc. Mag., 5(1), 23–28.
Sahin, O., Siems, R., Stewart, R., and Porter, M. G. (2016). “Paradigm shift to enhanced water supply planning through augmented grids, scarcity pricing and adaptive factory water: A system dynamics approach.” Environ. Modell. Software, 75, 348–361.
Sebri, M. (2014). “A meta-analysis of residential water demand studies.” Environ. Develop. Sustainability, 16(3), 499–520.
Siano, P. (2014). “Demand response and smart grids: A survey.” Renewable Sustainable Energy Rev., 30, 461–478.
Sonderlund, A. L., Smith, J. R., Hutton, C. J., Kapelan, Z., and Savic, D. (2016). “Effectiveness of smart meter-based consumption feedback in curbing household water use: Knowns and unknowns.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04016060.
Strong, A., and Goemans, C. (2015). “The impact of real-time quantity information on residential water demand.” Water Resour. Econ., 10(1), 1–13.
Thames Water. (2005). “Thames tideway strategic study. cost benefit working group report.” Reading, U.K.
Thames Water. (2014). “Final water resources management plan 2015–2040.” Reading, U.K.
Thames Water. (2015). “Our charges for household customers 2015/16.” ⟨http://www.thameswater.co.uk/tw/common/downloads/literature-water-waste-water-charges/Our_Charges_2015⟩ (Nov. 18, 2015).
Tilmant, A., Pinte, D., and Goor, Q. (2008). “Assessing marginal water values in multipurpose multireservoir systems via stochastic programming.” Water Resour. Res., 44(12), W12431.
Vašak, M., Banjac, G., Baotić, M., and Matuško, J. (2014). “Dynamic day-ahead water pricing based on smart metering and demand prediction.” Procedia Eng., 89(1), 1031–1036.
Vicente, D. J., Garrote, L., Sánchez, R., and Santillán, D. (2016). “Pressure management in water distribution systems: Current status, proposals, and future trends.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 04015061.
Visit England. (2016). “England tourism factsheet: April 2016.” Visit Britain, London.
Ward, F. A., and Pulido-Velazquez, M. (2012). “Economic costs of sustaining water supplies: Findings from the Rio Grande.” Water Resour. Manage., 26(10), 2883–2909.
Weber, M. A., and Berrens, R. P. (2006). “Value of instream recreation in the sonoran desert.” J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 53–60.
Worthington, A. C., and Hoffman, M. (2008). “An empirical survey of residential water demand modelling.” J. Econ. Surv., 22(5), 842–871.
Yang, Y.-C. E., Cai, X., and Stipanović, D. M. (2009). “A decentralized optimization algorithm for multiagent system-based watershed management.” Water Resour. Res., 45(8), W08430.
Young, R. A. (1996). “Water economics.” Chapter 3, Water resources handbook, L. W. Mays, ed., McGraw-Hill Education, New York.

Information & Authors

Information

Published In

Go to Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management
Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management
Volume 144Issue 5May 2018

History

Received: Nov 15, 2016
Accepted: Aug 11, 2017
Published online: Mar 8, 2018
Published in print: May 1, 2018
Discussion open until: Aug 8, 2018

Authors

Affiliations

Research Associate, School of Mechanical, Aerospace and Civil Engineering, Univ. of Manchester, Manchester M13 9PL, U.K. (corresponding author). ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-1374-4992. E-mail: [email protected]
Julien J. Harou [email protected]
Professor, School of Mechanical, Aerospace and Civil Engineering, Univ. of Manchester, Manchester M13 9PL, U.K. E-mail: [email protected]
Manuel Pulido-Velazquez [email protected]
Professor, Research Institute of Water and Environmental Engineering, Universitat Politècnica de València, Camí de Vera s/n, 46022 Valencia, Spain. E-mail: [email protected]
Evgenii S. Matrosov [email protected]
Research Fellow, School of Mechanical, Aerospace and Civil Engineering, Univ. of Manchester, Manchester M13 9PL, U.K. E-mail: [email protected]
Paola Garrone [email protected]
Professor, Dept. of Management, Economics and Industrial Engineering, Politecnico di Milano, Via Lambruschini 4/b, 20156 Milano, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]
Riccardo Marzano [email protected]
Postdoctoral Researcher, Dept. of Management, Economics and Industrial Engineering, Politecnico di Milano, Via Lambruschini 4/b, 20156 Milano, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]
Antonio Lopez-Nicolas [email protected]
Ph.D. Researcher, Research Institute of Water and Environmental Engineering, Universitat Politècnica de València, Camí de Vera s/n, 46022 Valencia, Spain. E-mail: [email protected]
Andrea Castelletti [email protected]
Associate Professor, Dept. of Electronics, Information, and Bioengineering, Politecnico di Milano, P.za Leonardo da Vinci, 32, 20133 Milano, Italy. E-mail: [email protected]
Andrea-Emilio Rizzoli [email protected]
Professor, Dalle Molle Institute for Artificial Intelligence Research, Università della Svizzera Italiana/Scuola Universitaria Professionale della Svizzera Italiana, 6928 Manno, Switzerland. E-mail: [email protected]

Metrics & Citations

Metrics

Citations

Download citation

If you have the appropriate software installed, you can download article citation data to the citation manager of your choice. Simply select your manager software from the list below and click Download.

Cited by

View Options

Media

Figures

Other

Tables

Share

Share

Copy the content Link

Share with email

Email a colleague

Share